L. Randall Wray is a professor of economics at the University of Missouri-Kansas City.
Around two
years ago, you pointed to an economic error in R & R paper. You said (*) that
correlation doesn’t imply causality. What do you think today in the face of the
new debate on coding error triggered by a book review?
Yes, I
co-authored a critique with Yeva Nersisyan that pointed to three major errors.
(See here)
First, the notion that one can simply aggregate across 800 years of data (from
a variety of sources) and countries with very different monetary and fiscal
policy arrangements to obtain a debt ratio threshold beyond which growth slows
is highly questionable. Why should we believe the experience of a weak feudal
government operating with a gold standard sheds light on a modern sovereign
government that issues its own floating currency? The short answer is that we
should not.
Second, the
authors did not provide clear details that would allow one to separate
governments that issued debt in foreign currency versus those that only issued
debt in their own currency. They did not indicate which were on gold standards
or had pegged exchange rates. In our view, that matters critically. A sovereign
government that issues its own currency cannot be forced into involuntary
default on debt denominated in that currency; it can always make payments in
its own currency—a point recognized even by Alan Greenspan. On the other hand,
countries that peg to gold or foreign currencies are often forced to abandon
the peg, which is a technical default. And governments that issue debt in
foreign currency are often forced into default. R&R simply lumped all this
together because they apparently do not understand that these arrangements
matter.
Third, we
suspected that their results were driven by a few outliers. Further, you would
need a lot more information to determine the cause and effect relation: does
slow growth lead to rising debt ratios, or does high debt lead to slow growth?
For example, it is quite clear that Japan’s high debt ratio today has resulted
from decades of slow growth (its debt ratio was not high before it went into
recession). For that reason, we wrote to them to get their data—to try to see
which national experiences drove their results, and to check for “reverse
causation”. They did not respond to our request.
And now we
know there was a fourth problem with their results: the data they used actually
did not support their results. They excluded data that conflicted with the
results they reported. In other words, the results are erroneous: they have no
evidence that high debt ratios lead to lower growth; the magic number—90% debt
ratio—was wrong all along.
Why did so
many economists and politicians believe in the first place in expansionary
austerity which is causing human suffering without an end in Europe today?
They
wanted to believe it. It fit with their neoliberal ideology. Of course, this
happens all the time. They should now be embarrassed. There is no such thing as
expansion through fiscal austerity. It has never worked; there is no evidence
to support the theory. I do believe that in some cases countries can still grow
IN SPITE OF fiscal austerity. But they do not grow BECAUSE OF fiscal austerity.
And, finally, R&R have not shown that high debt ratios by sovereign
governments that issue debt in their own currency lead to fiscal crises. There
isn’t evidence in support of this neoliberal belief, and everyone should be
skeptical of the claims of deficit hysterians.
What is the
single most effective tool to support aggregate demand and tackle the mass
unemployment in a depressed economy?
As Yeva
and I argued in another piece,
in a depressed economy, you need fiscal expansion. By that I do not necessarily
mean “priming the pump”—generalized spending. I think it is much better to aim
the spending where it is most needed, and that usually means more jobs. Hence,
I favor spending directly on job creation.
Here’s the
problem. You do need fiscal policy space to engage in stimulus. Countries with
their own floating currency have that space, so they can always choose to spend
more to stimulate demand. Countries that peg to gold or other currencies may
not have the space. And unfortunately, European countries that dropped their
own currencies in order to adopt the foreign Euro currency do not individually
have the policy space. So for the EMU, the fiscal expansion can only come from
the center. And that is the big problem that has not been resolved. To make
matters worse, the Troika still believes in expansionary austerity—a non
sequitur. And so they will continue to impose austerity and suffering on the
population.
Thank you
very much.
Senior
Scholar L. Randall Wray is a professor
of economics at the University of Missouri-Kansas City. His current research
focuses on providing a critique of orthodox monetary theory and policy and the
development of an alternative approach. He is using Minsky’s approach
to analyze the current global financial crisis.
(*) in FTD.
Keine Kommentare:
Kommentar veröffentlichen